Chillin'Competition

Relaxing whilst doing Competition Law is not an Oxymoron

Legitimate aims and restrictions by object (I): Sports, Wouters and Meca Medina

with 8 comments

A couple of months have passed since Superleague and ISU (as well as Royal Antwerp). One of the most recurrent issues in the stimulating commentary that followed the delivery of the rulings related to the interpretation of Wouters and Meca Medina.

The Court held that a practice that amounts to a restriction by object cannot escape Article 101(1) TFEU under the WoutersMeca Medina doctrine. In the words of the Court (in ISU):

‘113. By contrast, the case-law referred to in paragraph 111 of the present judgment [Wouters and Meca Medina] does not apply either in situations involving conduct which, far from merely having the inherent ‘effect’ of restricting competition, at least potentially, by limiting the freedom of action of certain undertakings, reveals a degree of harm in relation to that competition that justifies a finding that it has as its very ‘object’ the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition. Thus, it is only if, following an examination of the conduct at issue in a given case, that conduct proves not to have as its object the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition that it must then be determined whether it may come within the scope of that case-law […]’.

The Court’s position has been widely discussed. The interest in this aspect of the saga is not something I would have anticipated. As I understand it, Superleague and ISU are fully in line with the preceding case law. Contrary to what has been suggested, it does not seem to me that they reduce the scope of the WoutersMeca Medina doctrine. If anything, they streamline and clarify it.

It is true that the preceding case law had not expressly spelled out what Superleague and ISU did. Arguably, the idea that Wouters and Meca Medina are only relevant where the practice is not a ‘by object’ infringement was already implicit in the relevant judgments. Some leading experts have taken a different view, but it always seemed to me like the most reasonable understanding of the doctrine.

To understand the Court’s position, one must remember the basic premise of the doctrine: where a restraint is justified by the ‘pursuit of one or more legitimate objectives in the public interest‘, it falls outside the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU altogether (that is, it does not restrict competition, whether by object or effect).

By definition, a restraint that is ‘genuinely necessary‘ to attain a set of regulatory goals that are not in and of themselves anticompetitive does not have, as its object, the restriction of competition.

In other words, if the restraint seeks, in a proportionate manner, to attain a one or more ‘legitimate objectives in the public interest‘, the object of the said restraint cannot be anticompetitive. It is in the nature of things: the object of the (legitimate) regulatory goals and the object of the ancillary restraint are one and the same. If the former is not restrictive by its very nature, neither is the latter.

The Court’s position (which, as explained above, is uncontroversial and expected) is particularly useful to illustrate, more broadly, its consistent approach to restrictions by object, which has been clarified in the past few years.

A first key idea one can draw from the case law is that restrictions by object are not abstract categories.

‘Price-fixing’ and ‘market sharing’ are not necessarily restrictive by object. In fact, these categories say very little about the nature of a practice in and of themselves. The Court has never been formalistic when ascertaining the object of agreements (for an extensive discussion, see here).

In a given economic and legal context, ‘price-fixing’ and ‘market sharing’ may even fall outside the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU altogether (which would be the case, for instance, if they relate to a transaction that pursues a legimate aim).

We are not short of examples in the case law showing that ‘price-fixing’ and ‘market sharing’ arrangements may escape the prohibition. Price-fixing (and coordinated output restrictions, no less) can very well fall outside the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU where they are part of the activities of a copyright collecting society. Think, in this sense, of the venerable judgment in Tournier.

Using language that reminds one of ISU and Superleague, the Court held in Tournier (para 31) that ‘[c]opyright-management societies pursue a legitimate aim when they endeavour to safeguard the rights and interests of their members vis-à-vis the users of recorded music. The contracts concluded with users for that purpose [which necessarily provide for price-fixing] cannot be regarded as restrictive of competition for the purposes of Article [101] unless the contested practice exceeds the limits of what is necessary for the attainment of that aim‘.

A more recent (and thus less venerable) example was provided by the Court in the recent judgment in EDP. In this ruling, the Court expressly held that a market sharing arrangement may fall outside the scope of the prohibition where it is ancillary to the main transaction (paras 87-94).

The second key idea is that the case law on restrictions by object is perhaps less obscure than assumed.

What ISU and Superleague show is that the question of whether a practice restricts competition by object is simpler than we tend to assume. The plain meaning of the word object (that is, the objective purpose or aim of an restraint) takes us a long way when evaluating whether an agreement is caught by Article 101(1) TFEU by its very nature. It is, by some distance, the single more reliable indicator.

In more precise terms, if a practice, objectively speaking, is a means to attain a legitimate regulatory objective (which in the sports arena may be to achieve competitive balance or to preserve the integrity of the competition) and is ancillary to it, it cannot be said to have an anticompetitive object.

Written by Pablo Ibanez Colomo

27 February 2024 at 3:45 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

Finding consensus in Article 102 cases (I)- When do the Bronner conditions apply? 

with 4 comments

Events and discussions around Article 102 are mushrooming in anticipation of the Commission’s draft guidelines on exclusionary abuses, which will likely be subject to public consultation during the summer. Over the next few days I will be taking part in two of those, namely at a BIICL workshop (The future of Article 102 TFEU) in Brussels (today) and at the GCLC’s annual conference in Bruges (Article 102 TFEU- Past, Present, Future) on 1-2 March. (Future conference titles may need to get more creative).

One of the elements that makes Article 102 a most attractive topic for both academic debates and litigation is the uncertainty as to what the law is. Still today, debates in both academic fora and individual cases tend to focus on what the law is (e.g. what is competition on the merits? when do we need to show foreclosure? what is foreclosure? what is the role of the AEC principle? do we need to conduct a counterfactual analysis in 102 cases?, etc), as opposed to on how the law should apply to a specific set of facts/evidence. This is remarkable, and arguably in no one’s interest (unless you’re into lawyering or legal blogging); enforcers, courts and companies would all benefit from a stable and predictable legal framework.

Having spent the past few years debating Article 102 both within and outside Courts, I have come to realize that, contrary to appearances, there is much more common ground and scope for consensus on the applicable legal framework than meets the eye. Most of the discussions on these topics tend to be polluted by a desire to influence, justify, secure or revert the outcome of individual cases, but when one forgets for a moment about specific cases, spaces for consensus start to emerge. To give you an example, after debating some of the major pending cases together in Court, Fernando Castillo and I had a recent debate on Article 102 issues where, after leaving case-specific discussions on the side, we were able to agree on some questions of principle. There is, after all, some truth to the idea that difficult cases make bad law, and all Article 102 cases tend to be difficult cases. 

This is all to say that the upcoming guidelines are a perfect opportunity to try to find and build on that common ground to clarify the law instead of to fight about it. In that spirit, we will be publishing a series of blog posts, and at some point a paper (which will also reflect the feedback we receive here) on how we can find consensus on Article 102 based on hopefully non-controversial principles already settled by the Courts. This is not about meeting in the middle, but about having an honest discussion based on an honest interpretation of the case law.

For the purposes of this first post, let me illustrate my point by reference to one of the debates by reference to one of the debates that has kept lawyers (including myself), courts and pundits busy for the past few years.

When do the Bronner conditions apply?

We have spent years debating whether the Bronner conditions should apply or not to margin squeeze, to constructive or passive refusals, to implicit or explicit requests/refusals, to self-preferencing, etc, but the CJEU’s position is clear, consistent and, I think, very hard to disagree with. 

According to the CJEU, the imposition of those conditions is necessary and justified where a finding of abuse “has the consequence of forcing an undertaking to conclude a contract with [a] competitor”, because “such an obligation is especially detrimental to the freedom of contract and the right to property of the dominant undertaking” (Slovak Telekom, para. 46). 

The CJEU said the same in Lithuanian Railways (para. 86) and in Deutsche Telekom (para. 46). The GC recently said the same in Bulgarian Energy Holdings (para. 257, also 258, 282 and 451). AG Saugmandsgaard Øe explained this perfectly in his Opinion in Slovak Telekom (para. 74). AG Rantos explained it perfectly in his Opinion in Lithuanian Railways (paras. 64, 81 and 85), and AG Kokott also explains it in her recent Opinion in Google Shopping (paras 84-86). As AG Kokott observes, “after all, every obligation which Article 102 TFEU imposes on that undertaking to grant access or to supply to its competitors comes with an interference with that right and that freedom and must therefore be carefully weighed up and justified”. 

What matters, in other (the Court’s) words, is whether intervention under competition law would have the consequence of depriving the dominant company of its freedom of contract and right to property, and not so much the labels that one may use to describe the conduct at issue (e.g. constructive vs outright refusals). The European Commission has practically always held the same view; see for example the Commission’s written pleadings in Slovak Telekom, where the Commission explained to the Court that “the distinction (…) between outright refusals and constructive refusal is misleading. The true distinction is whether the circumstances are such that a compulsory access obligation stems directly from Article 102 TFEU, with failure to grant such access constituting an abuse (…)” (para. 34).

Many people would probably expect me to say that I disagree because this is an excessively narrow interpretation of the Bronner case law, but I don’t. Relying on the practical consequences of competition law intervention, as opposed to on formal categorizations, is the perfect way to ensure legal certainty and respect of fundamental rights, and to avoid an unduly wide or narrow application of those conditions. I have no trouble, for example, with the idea that margin squeeze needs to be subject to a different standard, which some have strongly disputed. In my mind the Court of Justice’s case law on this point is clear and sensible.

This, of course, does not mean that we will not continue to disagree on how this test applies to individual cases. For example, I may see weak spots in AG Kokott’s Opinion in Shopping (e.g. at paras. 125-126, where she appears to reason that it’s not necessary to ascertain whether the Bronner conditions should apply to the case at issue because they are not applicable, which seems circular) [I might not be objective, though, given that I represent one of the parties, so take my views with a pinch of salt, read it yourself and form your own opinion]. I, however, would not dispute AG Kokott’s general interpretation of the relevant case law because, again, case-specific disagreements driven by preferred outcomes should not be an obstacle to agreeing on what the law is. 

To be continued…

Written by Alfonso Lamadrid

21 February 2024 at 9:06 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

NEW PAPER | Data leveraging in energy markets in the aftermath of EDF and ENEL

leave a comment »

I have just uploaded on ssrn a paper (see here), written jointly with Alexis Brunelle (Autorité de la concurrence), Adrien de Hauteclocque (General Court of the EU and Florence School of Regulation) and Juliette Ogez (Autorité de la concurrence).

The piece will be coming out in the Handbook of Energy and Competition Law, edited by Leigh Hancher and Ignacio Herrera Anchustegui.

The paper revolves around two relatively recent cases involving data leveraging by incumbents in the energy sector. One of them is EDF (available here in French). This case was settled (with commitments) by the French competition authority back in 2022.

The second is ENEL (aka Servizio Elettrico Nazionale), originally decided by the Italian authority (the decision, in Italian, is available here). This case is best known for the preliminary ruling delivered by the Court of Justice (and discussed abundantly on this blog; see here, here and here).

The two cases are interesting on a number of fronts. They show how competition law can act as a safety net in recently liberalised industries (regulation can rarely ever anticipate or adress every single leveraging strategy).

EDF and ENEL also illustrate, second, the role that data can play in network industries. In both, it was a central aspect of the contentious behaviour.

Finally, the discussion is useful in that it requires one to revisit some of the fundamental principles in EU competition law, in particular competition on the merits and the analysis of anticompetitive effects. In fact, the two cases provide concrete instances of conduct that depart, by their very nature, from legitimate competition on the merits.

My co-authors and I would be really keen to get your thoughts on the paper. Do not hesitate to send us your comments.

Written by Pablo Ibanez Colomo

20 February 2024 at 3:32 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

The dangers of the notion of competition on the merits (and how to address them)

with 6 comments

The notion of competition on the merits (which I recently discussed in a paper here) would have been aptly described, until recently, as a relic of the early days of Article 102 TFEU. Just take a look at the case law of the past decade.

Landmarks from Deutsche Telekom and TeliaSonera to Intel and Slovak Telekom (not to mention the Post Danmark saga) ignored competition on the merits altogether. At best, the notion featured in the old formulas taken from early judgments. In practice, however, it played no role in the assesment.

There was a good reason why competition on the merits was disregarded in the long decade preceding Servizio Elettrico Nazionale. It had been accepted that most potentially abusive conduct is normal (by which I mean that it has a pro-competitive potential and that it is also routinely implemented by non-dominant firms).

For instance, the fact that a practice is, objectively speaking, a product improvement does not insulate it from scrutiny under Article 102 TFEU.

The main conclusion to draw from this consistent case law is that authorities cannot be required to show that a practice is an abnormal method of competition. Typically, an abuse can be established by showing that the contentious conduct is a source of actual or potential effects in the relevant economic and legal context.

Things have changed. All of a sudden, it looks as if the notion of competition on the merits is central to the interpretation of Article 102 TFEU. Deciding whether or not a practice is a legitimate method of competition now seems to be a key step in an abuse of dominance investigation (at least in some quarters).

As I argue in my paper, this perception is not only difficult to square with the case law, but it is also dangerous. It is dangerous in the sense that it risks taking law and policy back to the stone age. If not handled with care, competition on the merits may pave the way for the comeback of intuitive and informal analysis (which we thought had left us for good).

Consider the example of tying. Is this practice a ‘normal’ method of competition? It certainly is. Decades of experience and formal analysis show that it is potentially pro-competitive (we know that the combination of products and of features can improve the competitive process in several ways).

We also know that tying is pervasive in the economy. Both dominant and non-dominant firms routinely engage in tying, typically for non-sinister reasons. In other words (and to come back to the vocabulary used in Servizio Elettrico Nazionale), non-dominant firms can (and do) ‘replicate’ the conduct.

In fact, tying illustrates (perhaps better than any other practice) the limits of the ‘replicability test’ at which the Court hinted in Servizio and reveals, moreover, that the said test is underinclusive (it would lead to Type II errors).

In spite of the above, tying can be caught by Article 102 TFEU if, absent an objective justification, it is a source of actual or potential anticompetitive effects in the relevant economic and legal context.

The key consideration is not whether this practice can be categorised as falling outside the scope of competition on the merits, but whether, in a particular factual scenario, it causes net harm on the competitive process. An authority (or claimant) cannot and should not be expected to establish, in addition to the effects, that tying is at odds with competition on the merits.

This (well-established and uncontroversial) analytical framework risks being replaced by intuitive, informal analysis that revolves around deciding whether tying is a legitimate method of competition (or an abnormal one instead).

We already have examples of this intuitive interpretation of Article 102 TFEU. Coming back to the example of tying, some commentators have argued that this practice is not competition on the merits insofar as it deprives customers of choice (presumably the possibility of acquiring the tying product without the tied product).

Crucially, these intuitive claims are made without the support of any theoretical and/or empirical evidence. They are an expression of what we might call a ‘vibes-based approach’ to the interpretation of Article 102 TFEU.

My point in this post is that this ‘vibes-based approach’ is not only at odds with the case law (the Court has consistently emphasised the importance of experience and economic analysis when construing competition law provisions), but also risky.

First, intuition and informal analysis would make enforcement less rigorous. Second, they would make it less predictable, since the established body of knowledge may be disregarded altogether in favour of ad hoc, impressionistic evaluations. Third, they would pave the way for the arbitrary and capricious interpretation of the law. ‘Vibes’, by definition, cannot be meaningfully challenged before a court, because they are just that – vibes.

Finally (and more importantly), intuition and informal analysis distract us from the fundamental substantive issues. Rather than focusing on the net impact of a practice on the competitive process, the assessment would turn into pigeon-holing and semantic discussions.

What is the solution? How can the risks associated with the notion of competition on the merits be addressed?

The solution, I argue in my paper, is simple: it is a matter of following the case law. As far as the vast majority of practices are concerned, the question of whether a practice is, in principle, an expression of competition on the merits and that of whether it can cause anticompetitive effects are one and the same. Showing the latter implicitly proves the former.

This is not only the approach that the Court has consistently followed since the early 2010s, but the one that ensures that law and policy remains rigorous and grounded on the best available expertise. Authorities (which would not be wasting precious resources arbitrarily categorising practices) would also gain from this approach (as would the system as a whole).

Written by Pablo Ibanez Colomo

14 February 2024 at 3:18 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

Announcing the Winner and Finalists of Chillin’Competition’s 4th Rubén Perea Award

leave a comment »

On 1 April 2020 we lost Rubén Perea, a truly extraordinary young man who was about to start a career in competition law. We decided to set up an award to honour his memory, and to recognize the work of other promising competition lawyers/economists under 30. EVP Vestager kindly agreed to deliver this Award.

Today we are announcing the winner and runners-ups of the 4th edition of this award. The winner of the 4th (2023) Rubén Perea Award is…

MUHAMMED MUSTAFA POLAT for his paper “Unraveling Labor Market Collusion: A Comprehensive Analysis Under EU Competition Law “.

The Jury also selected 5 other papers of particularly high quality. JECLAP will publish these papers in a special issue. These finalists and selected papers are:

  • Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence and EU Competition Law: Mandatory Due Diligence Collaborations Under the EU Corporate Sustainability Due Diligence Directive Exempted from the Application of Article 101 (1) TFEU?” (by Lois Elshof)
  • Efficiency and Capabilities in Article 102 TFEU“ (by Selçukhan Ünekbaş)
  • Reconsidering the Limits of EU Competition Law on the IP-Competition Interface” (by Quentin Schäfer)
  • Access to Environmental Justice under the Aarhus Convention: Evaluating the Contemporary Hurdles for ENGOs in Challenging State Aid Decisions under EU Law “ (by Anna-Lici Scherer)
  • Competition and the Green Deal: a Study of Consumers WTP for CO2 Emissions Reduction in the Italian Car Market” (by Alessandra Catenazzo)

Our warmest congratulations go to Muhammed and the finalists. And thanks a million also to all those who submitted their work for this award. We received a large number of anonymous submissions; you truly made the Jury have a hard time.

This year’s jury composed of renown experts, some of whom were also friends, former teachers or colleagues of Rubén, namely Damien Gerard, Michele Piergiovanni, Gianni de Stefano, Lena Hornkohl, David Pérez de Lamo, Nicolas Fafchamps, Eugenia Brandimarte and myself (our gratitude goes to all of them for devoting part of their time to this project).

We will soon be announcing the 5th edition of the Rubén Perea Award. Stay tuned!

Written by Alfonso Lamadrid

8 February 2024 at 12:19 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

LSE Short Courses on Advanced EU Competition Law (May 2024) | Registration open

leave a comment »

Slowly but surely, the Short Course on Advanced EU Competition Law is becoming an annual tradition at LSE Law School. The details on the fourth (!) edition, to take place in May of this year, can be found here.

I have been encouraged by the interest it has sparked in the community (we have had a full house every time) and by the fact that exchanging views with the world of practice (there is always a great and balanced mix of civil servants and practitioners, both from law firms and in-house) is invariably enriching for an academic.

Just like the preceding ones, the fourth edition is designed with full-time professionals in mind. The course (16 hours in total) takes place online on Friday afternoon over four weeks (2pm-6pm London time; 3pm-7pm continental time).

The course is limited to around 25 participants to maximise interaction (and I can tell from experience that interaction was definitely maximised in the preceding years).

We will be addressing in a systematic way the many exciting developments that are transforming competition law across the board (agreements, abusive practices and merger control). The idea is to give you an updated account of the most recent developments and help you navigate them by providing an analytical framework.

As you will see in the course page, the precise dates are: 3rd, 10th, 17th and 24th May.

An LSE Certificate will be available upon completion, along with CPD points for practitioners.

If you have any questions about the organisational aspects of the two courses, do not hesitate to contact my colleague Amanda TinnamsA.Tinnams@lse.ac.uk.

Written by Pablo Ibanez Colomo

7 February 2024 at 5:54 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

Recent developments in EU Competition Law (9 February 2024- Hybrid event)

leave a comment »

Like every year, Fernando Castillo de la Torre (Director of the Competition team at the European Commission’s Legal Service) and Eric Gippini-Fournier (Competition Hearing Officer) have put together a one-afternoon seminar on recent developments in EU Competition Law as part of the annual IEB competition law course. The seminar will take place (under Chatham House rules) next Friday 9 February 2024 between 16 and 20.30 CET. If you’re in Madrid, you can attend in person but, if not, you can also join the discussion online.

For registrations, please write to competencia@ieb.es

More information on logistics is available here:

This is the program:

16:00 – 17:45: Cartel Policy today and tomorrow

Soledad Blanco Thomas, DG COMP

Marisa Tierno Centella, Director for Competition, CNMC

Johan Ysewyn, Partner, Covington & Burling

Peter Whelan, Professor, University of Leeds

18.00 – 19.30: Towards Article 102 Guidelines

Mark English, Partner, Garrigues

Cristina Sjödin, Member of the Legal Service, European Commission

Elena Zoido, Executive Vice President, Compass Lexecon

19.45 – 20.30: EU Competition Law and Sports; the December 2023 judgments in Superleague, ISU and Royal Antwerp

Alfonso Rincón, Partner, MLAB

Written by Alfonso Lamadrid

5 February 2024 at 9:04 am

Posted in Uncategorized

Launch of The New EU Competition Law (POSTPONED)

leave a comment »

We regret to inform you that we have been forced to postpone, due to illness, the even that we had scheduled for tomorrow to celebrate the launch of Pablo’s new book.

We will reschedule once Pablo is back on his feet, which we all trust will happen very soon!

Written by Alfonso Lamadrid

10 January 2024 at 3:58 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

The New Competition Law (II): whatever happened to the ‘more economics-based approach’?

leave a comment »

I look forward to seeing many of you next Thursday in Brussels for the launch of The New EU Competition Law. The other half of Chillin’Competition, as well as other good friends of the blog, will be there. It promises to be fun.

The first post on the book addressed the institutional transformation that the EU competition law underwent with the adoption of Regulation 1/2003. Today’s entry focuses instead on the intellectual shifts that the discipline has experienced over the past 20 years, which I address in Chapter 2 of the book (‘The rise and decline of the “more economics-based approach”‘).

The ‘more economics-based approach’ was all the rage in the early 2000s. The modernisation of Articles 101 and 102 TFEU, which was the big buzzword at the time, referred both to the substantive and the institutional changes to the application of the two provisions.

In those days, it felt as if economic analysis was taking EU competition law to its own ‘end of history’. Articles 101 and 102 TFEU (in addition to merger control), it seemed, were changing for good. This is the context in which Christian Ahlborn and Jorge Padilla coined the term ‘Brussels consensus’ (see here for their original contribution) and captured the zeitgeist.

It does not feel this way anymore. If anything, the impression is that there a new consensus is forming around different ideas. Economic analysis is not absent from this emerging consensus: its role, however, is different.

What happened over the past decade? Why are the ideas driving the rise of the ‘more economics-based approach’ seemingly falling out of favour?

Chapter 2 explains that the key might lie with perceptions about what makes competition law enforcement legitimate.

The ‘more economics-based approach’ was, I argue, a rational response by the European Commission to a legitimacy crisis in the system. The authority understood that enforcement would not be accepted as legitimate if not informed by economic analysis.

Under the ‘Brussels consensus’ what matters, above all, is input and process. What matters, in other words, is that competition authorities rely on the best available expertise and that the assessment asks the right substantive questions. The outcome (that is, whether an infringement is established or not) is something about which the system is agnostic.

Things have changed over the past decade (I draw evidence in this sense, inter alia, from some of the leading conferences organised in Brussels).

With the rise of Big Tech, and under the influence of old and new ideas, what is expected from the competition law system is that it delivers. Enforcement is deemed legitimate, in other words, if it is able to enact change.

Many stakeholders are no longer satisfied with asking the right questions and pondering whether intervention is warranted in the specific circumstances of the case. The expectation is that authorities deliver the palpable, timely restructuring of digital and other markets.

Outcomes (as opposed to input and process) are now the driving force under the emerging consensus. A number of important consequences follow. One of them is that the relationship with economic analysis changes. Formal economics does not act as a constraint on enforcement (or not in the same way it did under the ‘Brussels consensus’).

A second one is that, if the existing tools do not deliver the desired outcomes (or do not do so in a timely and/or effective manner), then new tools are introduced. This is the background against which we must make sense of the adoption of the Digital Markets Act.

A third one is that the priorities change. A key tenet of the ‘Brussels consensus’ was scepticism vis-a-vis distributional issues, in particular in the context of Article 102 TFEU. The discipline would focus on exclusion, leaving the allocation of rents to other fields of law.

Not anymore: redistribution is front and centre of the new EU competition law, with all the fascinating substantive and institutional consequences that follow.

We will be discussing all the above, and much more, next week in Brussels. À bientôt, and all the best for 2024!

Written by Pablo Ibanez Colomo

5 January 2024 at 6:12 pm

Posted in Uncategorized

NEW PAPER | Competition on the merits

with 2 comments

What is competition on the merits? This is the question I seek to answer in my most recent paper, available here.

The notion of competition on the merits seemed irrelevant not so long ago (that is, before Servizio Elettrico Nazionale exposed a friction in the case law). Landmarks of the 2010s such as Post Danmark I, TeliaSonera or Intel went about applying Article 102 TFEU without paying much attention (if any) to this notion.

Competition on the merits is now back in all discussions (and, for some, central to determine whether or not a given practice amounts to an abuse). Against this background, the paper seeks to answer two interrelated questions. What is competition on the merits? Does Article 102 TFEU apply to normal conduct or is an abuse an inherently ‘abnormal’ or ‘wrongful’ act?

It makes sense to start with the second. An overview of the case law suggests that normal conduct can be subject to Article 102 TFEU. ‘Normal’, in this context, means that the strategy is potentially pro-competitive (that is, firms can have recourse to it for non-exclusionary reasons) and that can be implemented by both dominant and non-dominant firms (that is, it is not the exclusive province of the former).

Exclusive dealing, tying and rebates (not to mention a refusal to deal with a third party) are all normal in this sense. However, we know well that they may amount to an abuse of a dominant position where certain conditions are met.

How about competition on the merits? The paper explains that this notion has become an irritant in the case law, in the sense that it is a source of confusion and frictions.

Tensions can be explained in part by the fact that the notion of competition on the merits was introduced at a time when the prevailing ideas about abusive conduct were very different from today’s.

In the 1960s and 1970s, it was assumed that abusive practices could be identified ex ante and in the abstract. The underlying premise was that it was possible to draw a clear dividing line between unlawful conduct and legitimate expressions of competition on the merits.

The case law that followed (as well as the evolution of legal and economic thinking) moved away from these ideas. Whether or not most practices amount to an abuse is a context-specific exercise, not an abstract one detached from ‘all the circumstances’ surrounding their implementation.

If most practices are neither inherently good nor bad and the application of Article 102 TFEU is very much context-dependent, what is the contemporary role of competition on the merits?

My argument is that the notion of competition on the merits has role to play in the contemporary case law if it is interpreted in light of the ‘as efficient competitor’ principle (which has been a consistent feature in the judgments delivered over the past decade, including in yesterday’s ruling in Superleague).

Against this background, the argument provides a positive and a negative definition of the notion.

From a positive perspective, a dominant firm can be said to compete on the merits where it gets ahead in the marketplace with, inter alia, better, cheaper and/or more innovative goods or services.

The corollary to this positive definition is that, where the exclusion of a rival is attributable to the fact that the latter is less attractive along one or more parameters of competition, the practice is not abusive. Any exclusion would be the manifestation of competition on the merits.

From a negative perspective, a dominant firm does not compete on the merits in three instances.

First, where the practice has an anticompetitive object (that is, it makes no economic sense other than as a means to restrict competition). Pricing below average variable costs is the classic example in this regard.

Second, where the strategy involves the use of assets not developed on the merits (that is, assets that have been developed with State support, either in the form of State aid or the award of exclusive rights). In this instance, which was at stake in Post Danmark II, the ‘as efficient competitor’ principle would not be the benchmark against which the lawfulness of the practice is assessed.

Third, where the practice, while potentially pro-competitive, causes the exclusion of equally efficient rivals. In the latter, instance, the question of whether the behaviour is an expression of competition on the merits and that of whether it is exclusionary collapse into one and the same issue.

Based on the above, one can classify the case law in the manner you see on the Table below:

I would very much welcome your comments on the paper. As usual, I have nothing to disclose.

Written by Pablo Ibanez Colomo

22 December 2023 at 10:38 am

Posted in Uncategorized