AG Saugmandsgaard Øe in Case C-179/16, F Hoffmann La Roche v AGCM: a canonical approach to restrictions by object
It has taken us more than usual to discuss AG Saugmandsgaard Øe’s Opinion in Case C-179/16, which is the most recent Hoffmann-La Roche in town (and we had very good reasons to do so, as you will see below!). But here we are.
Above all, the Opinion is valuable due to the approach that the Advocate General follows to identify restrictions by object. Not because it introduces any innovations – he just follows the case law – but because of how clean the analysis is.
The dispute at stake in the case is useful to illustrate the way in which the Court goes about the divide between restrictions by object and effect. An excellent candidate for classroom discussions.
The venerable Consiglio di Stato referred five questions to the ECJ. The most interesting one concerned the lawfulness of a concerted practice aimed at emphasising that a medicinal product is ‘less safe or less efficacious’ than another one. According to the Italian competition authority, this concerted practice sought to artificially differentiate between two medicinal products and thus share markets.
The referring court mentions a valuable aspect pertaining to the ‘scientific context’ of the practice: the Consiglio di Stato adds that, at the time, there was no reliable scientific evidence either to support or refute the claim about the relative safety and efficacy of the product.
Is a concerted practice (or agreement) of this kind caught by Article 101(1) TFEU insofar as its object is to share markets?
How to identify restrictions by object: AG Saugmandsgaard Øe gives a concise and elegant answer
Commentators struggle to define the criteria to draw the line between restrictions by object and effect. The Opinion shows that the task should not be difficult.
AG Saugmandsgaard Øe’s approach captures the essence of the case law in a concise and elegant way. As he explains in para 148 of the Opinion, understanding the object of an agreement is all about making sense of its ‘economic function’, that is, of its objective rationale.
When making sense of the economic function of an agreement or concerted practice, it is useful to examine whether the conduct is a plausible means to achieve a pro-competitive objective. This is something that Alfonso and I emphasised in a piece we published last year, and to which the Advocate General refers in the Opinion (at footnote 96).
When there is a plausible pro-competitive explanation for the practice, the agreement or concerted practice is not restrictive by object. This is a point that has been confirmed very many times by the Court (Cartes Bancaires is just a recent and particularly obvious example). In any event, it is useful that the Advocate General engages with this question explicitly (as many judgments address it only implicitly).
The application of the framework to the facts at hand
How does the Advocate General apply the principles of the case law to the facts at hand? The question of whether the concerted practice restricts competition depends, in his view, on whether the information provided by the parties to the concerted practice is misleading.
- The concerted practice would be restrictive by object if the information about the efficacy and safety of the medicinal product is misleading.
- If the information turns out not to be misleading, the concerted practice would not be restrictive of competition (that is, it would fall outside the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU).
The Opinion makes a lot of sense to me. I fail to see how providing misleading information about a product can serve a pro-competitive rationale. This practice can only be plausibly explained as an attempt to reduce demand for one product (that is, as an attempt to restrict competition). The ‘by object’ label is thus entirely justified. This practice would be similar to the exchanges of information at stake in T-Mobile and Bananas.
Where the parties convey information that is not misleading, on the other hand, it makes sense to leave the concerted practice outside the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU. As the Advocate General points out in para 181, such a concerted practice would improve, rather than restrict, the conditions of competition prevailing on the relevant market. If that is so, it would be a plausible means to achieve a pro-competitive objective. In this sense, the practice would be similar to the exchange of information at stake in Asnef-Equifax, which was also found to escape the prohibition.
Lessons from the Opinion: effects-based approach and ‘object box’
Three ideas came to mind when reading the Opinion:
- The Court’s approach to the identification of ‘by object’ infringements is, and has always been, very ‘effects-based’.
- Human ingenuity is much larger than the ‘object box’ will ever be.
- The ‘effects-based’ approach is compatible with the ‘by object’ treatment of some practices
The concerted practice at stake in this case did not fall within any of the categories that are traditionally associated with ‘by object’ infringements (price-fixing, market sharing and so on).
Does this fact exclude the qualification of the agreement as restrictive by object? Of course not. As rightly explained in the Opinion – at para 150 – the form of a practice has never been enough to decide whether an agreement amounts to a ‘by object’ infringement.
The Court, by emphasising the need to consider the nature of the agreement, its content, and the economic and legal context of which it is part, has always placed substance above form (Allianz Hungaria, among many others, comes to mind). In other words, the Court has always rejected the ‘form-based’ approach to the analysis of ‘by object’ infringements.
I tell myself that ‘effects-based’ approach is perhaps a misnomer. I would rather call it the ‘substance-over-form’ approach.
An important consequence of the approach followed by the Court: the famous ‘object box’ is both over-inclusive and under-inclusive.
The ‘object box’ is over-inclusive in the sense that even price-fixing or market sharing can, in a given economic and legal context, fall outside the scope of Article 101(1) TFEU (e.g. Tournier and Ideal Standard). The Court has consistently held, since Societe Technique Miniere, that a restriction of competition cannot be established in the abstract (i.e. it has never ever been enough to cry ‘price fixing’).
The ‘object box’ is under-inclusive in the sense that ‘by object’ infringements can take many new forms – never underestimate the ingenuity of companies that are determined to restrict competition! F Hoffmann La Roche v AGCM is a wonderful example in this regard.
Against this background the question is: should we keep expanding the ‘object box’ with every new case that does not fit within existing categories or should we throw the box away as an imperfect and potentially misleading proxy? Discuss.
Finally: for some people, the ‘effects-based’ (‘substance-over-form’, I mean) approach means the demise of ‘by object’ infringements. I cannot disagree more.
The ‘substance-over-form’ approach is certainly compatible with the ‘by object’ treatment of some practices. If it turns out that an agreement serves no pro-competitive objective, there is no point in requiring anticompetitive effects. I would say more: requiring evidence of anticompetitive effects in such a case would make no sense.
Pablo, I see two problems with your theory. The first (as we have discussessed before) is that the Court never actually said that it was looking for pro-competitive justifications at the stage of determining whether something has an anticompetitive object. I agree that reading between the lines this is clearly a relevant factor, but if the Court was using this as its main test, why would it not say so? I understand that you don’t feel too concerned by this because you are convinced that the case law of the Court can be entirely explained by the use of this criteria. But if you had to plead a case tomorrow before the Court, would you really go for this first, or would you go for the (admittedly unhelpful) “sufficient degree of harm” criteria actually laid out in Cartes Bancaires? Second, perhaps more problematic (at least to practictioners such as myself), your theory reverses the burden of the proof. Who can show that there is a procompetitive rationale if it isn’t the parties? If the parties fail to convince the EC about this procompetitive rationale, should that be the end of the story or should the EC actually prove something? In any event, congratulations on being quoted, the paper is really worth a read.
Adrien Giraud
17 October 2017 at 2:55 pm
Hi Adrien! It is great to have you back.
What matters to me is that the Court has consistently tried to identify the objective purpose of agreements and that, whenever it has identified a plausible pro-competitive rationale, it has concluded that the agreement under consideration does not have as its object the restriction of competition. A few examples:
– Pronuptia: the Court concludes that franchising agreements allow the franchisor to expand its business without investing its own capital and benefit franchisees who would otherwise lack the necessary expertise and know-how to run the business. In this light, franchising is found not to have an anticompetitive object.
– BAT (Toltecs-Dorcet): the Court rules that a trade mark delimitation agreement is not restrictive of competition where its objective purpose is to avoid confusion and conflict between the parties (and, conversely, is prohibited where its aim is to divide up markets or restrict competition in any other way).
– Delimitis: exclusive dealing obligations are found to benefit both the supplier and the distributor (one secures access to outlets and is able to plan its production more effectively; the other secures access to supplies in beneficial terms) and are not deemed to have an anticompetitive object as a result.
– Remia: a no-compete obligation in the context of the sale of a business is deemed pro-competitive and thus not restrictive of competition where its objective purpose is to allow the buyer to preserve the goodwill associated with the business.
– Asnef-Equifax: the registers at stake in the case are deemed pro-competitive in the sense that they increase the information available to credit institutions, and therefore not ‘by object’.
– Pierre Fabre: the Court refers to the legitimate aim of the agreement, which excludes the ‘by object’ qualification.
I could go on but I think the message is clear. Even Cartes Bancaires is best rationalised in light of this case law (I agree in this regard with AG Saugmandsgaard Øe, who makes the same point). ‘Sufficient degree of harm’ is nothing but a formula first used in Societe Technique Miniere. The key in Cartes Bancaires – remember the first Chillin’ event? – is para 74: the Court notes that the contentious clauses served a pro-competitive aim and thus were not restrictive by object.
As you can see, if I were before a court I would refer to the long and consistent line of case law that supports this conclusion.
On the burden of proof: it is clear that the legal burden of establishing the infringement lies with the Commission. It is also clear (Murphy, paras 140 and 143) that the parties may put forward evidence relating to the economic and legal context that shows that the agreement does not have a restrictive object. I would say it is important, in this regard, to avoid conflating the legal and evidential burden of proof.
Thanks a million again for sharing your thoughts!
Pablo Ibanez Colomo
17 October 2017 at 4:10 pm
[…] AG Saugmandsgaard Øe in Case C-179/16, F Hoffmann La Roche v AGCM: a canonical approach to restrict… It has taken us more than usual to discuss AG Saugmandsgaard Øe’s Opinion in Case C-179/16, which is the most recent Hoffmann-La Roche in town (and we had very good reasons to do so, as you will see below!). But here we are… Pablo Ibanez Colomo (Chilling Competition) Fred S. McChesney In Memoriam: Honorable Man and Incisive Scholar It was with much sadness that I learned of the all-too-early death of Fred McChesney, whom I have known since the time that he spent at the University of Chicago Law School in the early 1980s when he visited on our faculty… Richard Epstein (Truth on the Market) Government Wins Finders Keepers: Criminal Forfeiture Cannot Be Used to Repay a Las Vegas Debt What happens if a defendant’s cash is subject to forfeiture but he also owes someone else money? Who gets the forfeited cash? Sara Kropf (Grand Jury Target) China’s new Anti-unfair Competition Law redefines bribery China’s new Anti-unfair Competition Law (the New Law) was promulgated by the Standing Committee of the National People’s Congress on 4 November 2017 and will take effect from 1 January 2018, by which date the current version of the law promulgated back in 1993 will cease to be effective… Norton Rose Fulbright Dawn raids in Poland – tighter rules on the gathering of electronic evidence On March 7, 2017, the Polish Court of Competition and Consumer Protection, the (“CCCP“), issued an important judgment regarding the powers of the Polish Competition Authority, the (“PCA“), to search IT systems and hardware (e-mails and hard disks) during dawn raids… Piotr Skurzyński, Maciej Gac (Kluwer Competition – Hogan Lovells) Third Circuit Sets Out Specialized Standard for Summary Judgment in Antitrust Cases Involving Parallel Conduct by Oligopolists In my last post, I wrote about the difficulties that antitrust plaintiffs face in getting to trial with claims based on circumstantial evidence. I discussed a decision of the federal district court in Chicago in a long-running class action against paper companies for conspiring to raise prices for containerboard provides an example of the… Jeffrey May (Wolters Kluwer – Antitrust Connect) The FTC should address how (and whether) it assesses causation as it looks to define “informational injury” The FTC will hold an “Informational Injury Workshop” in December “to examine consumer injury in the context of privacy and data security.” Defining the scope of cognizable harm that may result from the unauthorized use or third-party hacking of consumer information is, to be sure, a crucial inquiry, particularly as ever-more information is stored digitally… Geoffrey Manne & Kristian Stout (Truth on the Market) Are Restaurant No-Tipping Policies the Product of an Antitrust Conspiracy? In July of 2013, Danny Meyer, the CEO of the Union Square Hospitality Group, tweeted that he was considering eliminating tipping at his restaurants and solicited the opinion of other restaurant owners… by Jamison Davies and Robert P. LoBue (Antitrust Update) Welcome clarifications by the EU Court on the concept of excessive pricing On the 14 September, the Court of Justice of the European Union provided detailed guidance on the concept of excessive pricing under Article 102 TFEU, in response to questions posed by the Latvian Supreme Court. Kevin Coates, Siobhan Kahmann (Covington & Burling – Kluwer Competition) Imminent Australian competition law changes present new risks and opportunities Two laws to substantially amend the Competition and Consumer Act 2010 have now been passed in Parliament… Norton Rose Fulbright […]
Blog O’ Blogs November | Competition Policy International
3 July 2019 at 2:55 pm